Ed Kleinbard calls out “dynamic scoring”

January 3rd, 2015 at 10:15 am

There are many strong, substantive reasons to be worried about the use of “dynamic scoring” by the new Republican Congress. As Ed Kleinbard tells it in today’s NYT, the new majority is instructing the official scorekeepers of the revenue implications of tax changes to employ models that incorporate macroeconomic feedback.

As I argued here, such a move engenders at least two big concerns. First, there’s the uncertainty of the estimates, providing a plum opportunity for cherry picking:

Dynamic scoring calls for adding macroeconomic impacts to budget estimates. If, for example, your model of the economy is jiggered to show that cutting taxes boosts productivity, labor supply, and growth, then said growth can be tapped to offset the revenue lost by the tax cut. CBO doesn’t go there, because there’s insufficient evidence that such macroeconomic feedback effects can be reliably estimated (CBO does allow for some behavioral responses to tax changes, such as timing changes in realizing capital gains).

Thus, dynamic scoring that correctly reflects this uncertainty returns a range of results—that’s what I mean by it gives you more numbers. For example, a dynamic score of Rep. Dave Camp’s tax reform plan estimated that it would raise the level of GDP over ten years by between nothing (0.1%) and a lot (1.6%). Guess which end of that spectrum fans of his plan would choose to highlight?

Or, as Ed puts it, dynamic scoring provides us with “…greater exposure to the risk of a political thumb on the scale.”

The second problem, well covered by Ed, is that the R’s obviously hope that dynamic scoring will provide them the cover they need to cut taxes in ways that the current scoring approach will not (though I should note here that David Wessel disagrees–he doesn’t think these scores will differ enough from current methods to provide such cover; I’m with Ed on this). That leads to larger budget deficits and since tax increases are off the table with this crowd, that means greater pressure on the spending side of the budget.

Ed:

When revenues do in fact decline and deficits rise, those same proponents will push for steep cuts in government insurance or investment programs, because they will claim that the models demand it. That is what lies inside the Trojan horse of dynamic scoring.

My personal opinion on all this: the change in the scoring rules is an effort to smooth the way to “tax reform” and the less we hear about “tax reform” in this Congress the better. Sure, the tax code could use some work, but the ideologies of the players involved leads me to worry that we’d be very lucky to come out of any reform efforts with revenue neutrality and more likely to lose revenue. Given the challenges we face going forward, from climate change to the aging of the population to infrastructure needs to poverty to needed human capital investments, that’s an unacceptable outcome.

 

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

3 comments in reply to "Ed Kleinbard calls out “dynamic scoring”"

  1. Larry Signor says:

    Even dairy farmers know “Dynamic Scoring” is BS. If I feed my cows less grain this month, my feed bill will go down. That is great, until my milk check comes next month and I don’t have enough revenue to by an adequate supply of grain to produce milk. Who thinks this stuff up?


  2. Diogenes says:

    in an effort to test whether dynamic scoring is a better way to model the economy, can one go back and apply dynamic scoring techniques to policy proposals from the past? Since we have the actual data of what actually happened, then we could compare the CBO’s scoring to the dynamic scoring results and see which one comes closest to reality…


Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.